petermartell-blog
petermartell-blog
Peter Martell
534 posts
Hi, I'm Pete and that's my tumblr, here you'll find design, crafts and other amazing stuff i like.
Don't wanna be here? Send us removal request.
petermartell-blog · 1 year ago
Text
Il lusso è la manifestazione della ricchezza incivile che vuole impressionare chi è rimasto povero. È la manifestazione dell’importanza che viene data all’esteriorità e rivela la mancanza di interesse per tutto ciò che è elevazione culturale. È il trionfo dell’apparenza sulla sostanza.
Il lusso è una necessità per tanta gente che vuole avere una sensazione di dominio sugli altri. Ma gli altri se sono persone civili sanno che il lusso è finzione, se sogno ignoranti ammireranno e magari invidieranno chi vive nel lusso. Ma a chi interessa l’ammirazione degli ignoranti? Forse agli stupidi.
Infatti il lusso è una manifestazione di stupidità. Per esempio: a che cosa servono i rubinetti d’oro? Se da quei rubinetti d’oro esce un’acqua inquinata non è più intelligente, con la stessa spesa mettere un depuratore d’acqua e tenere i rubinetti normali? Il lusso è quindi l’uso sbagliato di materiali costosi che non migliora le funzioni. Quindi è una stupidaggine.
Naturalmente il lusso è legato all’arroganza e al dominio sugli altri. È legato a un falso senso di autorità. In antico l’autorità era lo stregone che aveva abbellimenti e oggetti che lui solo poteva avere. I re e i potenti erano vestiti con costosissimi tessuti e pellicce. Più il popolo era tenuto nell’ignoranza e più l’autorità si mostrava paludata di ricchezze.
E ancora oggi in molte nazioni si verificano queste manifestazione di apparenze miracolose. Contemporaneamente però nella gente sana si fa strada la conoscenza della realtà delle cose e non dell’apparenza. Il modello non è più il lusso e la ricchezza, non è più tanto l’avere quanto l’essere (per dirla con Erich Fromm).
Man mano che l’analfabetismo diminuisce l’autorità apparente cade e al posto dell’autorità imposta si considera l’autorità riconosciuta. Un cretino seduto su un grande trono poteva forse suggestionare in un tempo passato ma oggi, e soprattutto domani, si spera che non sia più così. Spariranno i troni e le poltrone di lusso per i dirigenti imposti, gli arredi speciali per i capi, le cattedre di lusso alzate su pedane di mogano, i paludamenti, i gradi, e tutto ciò che serviva per suggestionare.
Insomma, voglio dire che il lusso non è un problema di design.
Bruno Munari, Da cosa nasce cosa
0 notes
petermartell-blog · 1 year ago
Photo
Tumblr media
Singer, sedia per visite brevissime by Bruno Munari (Zanotta, 1945)
“Quando gli ospiti sono senza sorriso. Se la vita corre veloce, se il tempo accelera l’esistenza, se la frenesia ruba il tempo. Allora il sedile sarà inclinato, la seduta più corta, lo schienale più alto: la sedia sarà per visite brevissime.” Bruno Munari
via https://www.zanotta.it/it/prodotti/edizioni/singer
9 notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 1 year ago
Text
Tumblr media
How To Paint Pearls
by koklico
6K notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 1 year ago
Text
Tumblr media Tumblr media
14K notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 2 years ago
Text
Tumblr media
44 notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 2 years ago
Text
Poiché mi era permesso vedere cose che gli altri bambini non vedevano, apparivo sofisticato ai miei compagni di classe. E poiché stavo guardando i film più impegnativi della più grande epoca cinematografica della storia di Hollywood, avevano ragione, avevo ragione. Ad un certo punto, quando mi sono reso conto che stavo vedendo film che altri genitori non lasciavano vedere ai loro figli, ho chiesto informazioni a mia madre. Disse: "Quentin, mi preoccupa di più il fatto che tu guardi le notizie. Un film non ti farà del male".
Quentin Tarantino, Cinema speculation
97 notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 2 years ago
Photo
Tumblr media
581 notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 2 years ago
Text
Tumblr media
I believe I can fly
I believe I can touch the sky...
Finally got crazy arms and legs from Crazy Bricks (thanks to Kamino Bricks), just in time to join the Based on a Song challenge.
This is also my first entry to the Toy Photographers Bingo challenge.
Prompt: Minimalist ✔️
It is a year long challenge on Toy Photographers MeWe community and includes prizes by Lensbaby. Everyone is welcome to join!
Learn more about it here.
3K notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 2 years ago
Text
Tumblr media
1 note · View note
petermartell-blog · 2 years ago
Text
Social Quitting
Tumblr media
In “Social Quitting,” my latest Locus Magazine column, I advance a theory to explain the precipitous vibe shift in how many of us view the once-dominant social media platforms, Facebook and Twitter, and how it is that we have so quickly gone asking what we can do to get these services out of our lives to where we should go now that we’re all ready to leave them:
https://locusmag.com/2023/01/commentary-cory-doctorow-social-quitting/
The core of the argument revolves around surpluses — that is, the value that exists in the service. For a user, surpluses are things like “being able to converse with your friends” and “being able to plan activities with your friends.” For advertisers, surpluses are things like “being able to target ads based on the extraction and processing of private user data” and “being able to force users to look at ads before they can talk to one another.”
For the platforms, surpluses are things like, “Being able to force advertisers and business customers to monetize their offerings through the platform, blocking rivals like Onlyfans, Patreon, Netflix, Amazon, etc” and things like “Being able to charge more for ads” and “being able to clone your business customers’ products and then switch your users to the in-house version.”
Platforms control most of the surplus-allocating options. They can tune your feed so that it mostly consists of media and text from people you explicitly chose to follow, or so that it consists of ads, sponsored posts, or posts they think will “boost engagement” by sinking you into a dismal clickhole. They can made ads skippable or unskippable. They can block posts with links to rival sites to force their business customers to transact within their platform, so they can skim fat commissions every time money changes hands and so that they can glean market intelligence about which of their business customers’ products they should clone and displace.
But platforms can’t just allocate surpluses will-ye or nill-ye. No one would join a brand-new platform whose sales-pitch was, “No matter who you follow, we’ll show you other stuff; there will be lots of ads that you can’t skip; we will spy on you a lot.” Likewise, no one would sign up to advertise or sell services on a platform whose pitch was “Our ads are really expensive. Any business you transact has to go through us, and we’ll take all your profits in junk fees. This also lets us clone you and put you out of business.”
Instead, platforms have to carefully shift their surpluses around: first they have to lure in users, who will attract business customers, who will generate the fat cash surpluses that can be creamed off for the platforms’ investors. All of this has to be orchestrated to lock in each group, so that they won’t go elsewhere when the service is enshittified as it processes through its life-cycle.
This is where network effects and switching costs come into play. A service has “network effects” if it gets more valuable as users join it. You joined Twitter to talk to the people who were already using it, and then other people joined so they could talk to you.
“Switching costs” are what you have to give up when you leave a service: if a service is siloed — if it blocks interoperability with rivals — then quitting that service means giving up access to the people whom you left behind. This is the single most important difference between ActivityPub-based Fediverse services like Mastodon and the silos like Twitter and Facebook — you can quit a Fediverse server and set up somewhere else, and still maintain your follows and followers:
https://pluralistic.net/2022/12/23/semipermeable-membranes/#free-as-in-puppies
In the absence of interoperability, network effects impose their own switching cost: the “collective action problem” of deciding when to leave and where to go. If you depend on the people you follow and who follow you — for emotional support, for your livelihood, for community — then the extreme difficulty of convincing everyone to leave at the same time and go somewhere else means that you can be enticed into staying on a service that you no longer enjoy. The platforms can shift the surpluses away from you, provided that doing so makes you less miserable than abandoning your friends or fans or customers would. This is the Fiddler On the Roof problem: everyone stays put in the shtetl even though the cossacks ride through on the reg and beat the shit out of them, because they can’t all agree on where to go if they leave:
https://doctorow.medium.com/how-to-leave-dying-social-media-platforms-9fc550fe5abf
So the first stage of the platform lifecycle is luring in users by allocating lots of surplus to them — making the service fun and great and satisfying to use. Few or no ads, little or no overt data-collection, feeds that emphasize the people you want to hear from, not the people willing to pay to reach you.
This continues until the service attains a critical mass: once it becomes impossible to, say, enroll your kid in a little-league baseball team without having a Facebook account, then Facebook can start shifting its surpluses to advertisers and other business-users of the platform, who will pay Facebook to interpose themselves in your use of the platform. You’ll hate it, but you won’t leave. Junior loves little-league.
Facebook can enshittify its user experience because the users are now locked in, holding each other hostage. If Facebook can use the courts and technological countermeasures to block interoperable services, it can increase its users’ switching costs, producing more opportunities for lucrative enshittification without the risk of losing the users that make Facebook valuable to advertisers. That’s why Facebook pioneered so many legal tactics for criminalizing interoperability:
https://www.eff.org/cases/facebook-v-power-ventures
This is the second phase of the toxic platform life-cycle: luring in business customers by shifting surpluses from users to advertisers, sellers, etc. This is the moment when the platforms offer cheap and easy monetization, low transaction fees, few barriers to off-platform monetization, etc. This is when, for example, a news organization can tease an article on its website with an off-platform link, luring users to click through and see the ads it controls.
Because Facebook has locked in its users through mutual hostage-taking, it can pollute their feeds with lots of these posts to news organizations’ sites, bumping down the messages from its users’ friends, and that means that Facebook can selectively tune how much traffic it gives to different kinds of business customers. If Facebook wants to lure in sports sites, it can cram those sites’ posts into millions of users’ feeds and send floods of traffic to sports outlets.
Outlets that don’t participate in Facebook lose out, and so they join Facebook, start shoveling their content into it, hiring SEO Kremlinologists to help them figure out how to please The Algorithm, in hopes of gaining a permanent, durable source of readers (and thus revenue) for their site.
But ironically, once a critical mass of sports sites are on Facebook, Facebook no longer needs to prioritize sports sites in its users’ feeds. Now that the sports sites all believe that a Facebook presence is a competitive necessity, they will hold each other hostage there, egging each other on to put more things on Facebook, even as the traffic dwindles.
Once sports sites have taken each other hostage, Facebook can claw back the surplus it allocated to them and use it to rope in another sector — health sites, casual games, employment seekers, financial advisors, etc etc. Each group is ensnared by a similar dynamic to the one that locks in the users.
But there is a difference between users’ surpluses and business’s surpluses. A user’s surplus is attention, and there is no such thing as an “attention economy.” You can’t use attention to pay for data-centers, or executive bonuses, or to lobby Congress. Attention is not a currency in the same way that cryptos are not currency — it is not a store of value, nor a unit of exchange, nor or a unit of account.
Turning attention into money requires the same tactics as turning crypto into money — you have to lure in people who have real, actual money and convince them to swap it for attention. With crypto, this involved paying Larry David, Matt Damon, Spike Lee and LeBron James to lie about crypto’s future in order to rope in suckers who would swap their perfectly cromulent “fiat” money for unspendable crypto tokens.
With platforms, you need to bring in business customers who get paid in actual cash and convince them to give you that cash in exchange for ethereal, fast-evaporating, inconstant, unmeasurable “attention.” This works like any Ponzi scheme (that is, it works like cryptos): you can use your shareholders’ cash to pay short-term returns to business customers, losing a little money as a convincer that brings in more trade.
That’s what Facebook did when it sent enormous amounts of traffic to a select few news-sites that fell for the pivot to video fraud, in order to convince their competitors to borrow billions of dollars to finance Facebook’s bid to compete with Youtube:
https://doctorow.medium.com/metaverse-means-pivot-to-video-adbe09319038
This convincer strategy is found in every con. If you go to the county fair, you’ll see some poor bastard walking around all day with a giant teddy bear that he “won” by throwing three balls into a peach-basket. The carny who operated that midway game let him win the teddy precisely so that he would walk around all day, advertising the game, which is rigged so that no one else wins the giant teddy-bear:
https://boingboing.net/2006/08/27/rigged-carny-game.html
Social media platforms can allocate giant teddy-bears to business-customers, and it can also withdraw them at will. Careful allocations mean that the platform can rope in a critical mass of business customers and then begin the final phase of its life-cycle: allocating surpluses to its shareholders.
We know what this looks like.
Rigged ad-markets:
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Jedi_Blue
Understaffed content moderation departments:
https://www.dw.com/en/twitters-sacking-of-content-moderators-will-backfire-experts-warn/a-63778330
Knock-off products:
https://techcrunch.com/2021/12/08/twitter-is-the-latest-platform-to-test-a-tiktok-copycat-feature/
Nuking “trust and safety”:
https://www.reuters.com/technology/twitter-dissolves-trust-safety-council-2022-12-13/
Hiding posts that have links to rival services:
https://www.makeuseof.com/content-types-facebook-hides-why/
Or blocking posts that link to rival services:
https://pluralistic.net/2022/12/19/better-failure/#let-my-tweeters-go
Or worse, terminating accounts for linking to rival services:
https://blog.joinmastodon.org/2022/12/twitter-suspends-mastodon-account-prevents-sharing-links/
That is, once a platform has its users locked in, and has its business customers locked in, it can enshittify its service to the point of near uselessness without losing either, allocating all the useful surplus in the business to its shareholders.
But this strategy has a problem: users and business customers don’t like to be locked in! They will constantly try to find ways to de-enshittify your service and/or leave for greener pastures. And being at war with your users and business customers means that your reputation continuously declines, because every time a user or business customer figures out a way to claw back some surplus, you have to visibly, obviously enshittify your service wrestle it back.
Every time a service makes headlines for blocking an ad-blocker, or increasing its transaction fees, or screwing over its users or business customers in some other way, it makes the case that the price you pay for using the service is not worth the value it delivers.
In other words, the platforms try to establish an equilibrium where they only leave business customers and users with the absolute bare minimum needed to keep them on the service, and extract the rest for their shareholders. But this is a very brittle equilibrium, because the prices that platforms impose on their users and business customers can change very quickly, even if the platforms don’t do anything differently.
Users and business customers can revalue the privacy costs, or the risks of staying on the platform based on exogenous factors. Privacy scandals and other ruptures can make the cost you’ve been paying for years seem higher than you realized and no longer worth it.
This problem isn’t unique to social media platforms, either. It’s endemic to end-stage capitalism, where companies can go on for years paying their workers just barely enough to survive (or even less, expecting them to get public assistance and/or a side-hustle), and those workers can tolerate it, and tolerate it, and tolerate it — until one day, they stop.
The Great Resignation, Quiet Quitting, the mass desertions from the gig economy — they all prove the Stein’s Law: “Anything that can’t go on forever will eventually stop.”
Same for long, brittle supply-chains, where all the surplus has been squeezed out: concentrating all the microchip production in China and Taiwan, all the medical saline in Puerto Rico, all the shipping into three cartels… This strategy works well, and can be perfectly tuned with mathematical models that cut right to the joint, and they work and they work.
Until they stop. Until covid. Or war. Or wildfires. Or floods. Or interest rate hikes. Or revolution. All this stuff works great until you wake up and discover that the delicate balance between paying for guard labor and paying for a fair society has tilted, and now there’s a mob building a guillotine outside the gates of your luxury compound.
This is the force underpinning collapse: “slow at first, then all at once.” A steady erosion of the failsafes, flensing all the slack out of the system, extracting all the surpluses until there’s nothing left in the reservoir, no reason to stay.
It’s what caused the near-collapse of Barnes and Noble, and while there are plenty of ways to describe James Daunt’s successful turnaround, the most general characterization is, “He has reallocated the company’s surpluses to workers, readers, writers and publishers”:
https://tedgioia.substack.com/p/what-can-we-learn-from-barnes-and
A system can never truly stabilize. This is why utopias are nonsense: even if you design the most perfect society in which everything works brilliantly, it will still have to cope with war and meteors and pandemics and other factors beyond your control. A system can’t just work well, it has to fail well.
This is why I object so strenuously to people who characterize my 2017 novel Walkaway as a “dystopian novel.” Yes, the protagonists are eking out survival amidst a climate emergency and a failing state, but they aren’t giving up, they’re building something new:
https://locusmag.com/2017/06/bruce-sterling-reviews-cory-doctorow/
“Dystopia” isn’t when things go wrong. Assuming nothing will go wrong doesn’t make you an optimist, it makes you an asshole. A dangerous asshole. Assuming nothing will go wrong is why they didn’t put enough lifeboats on the Titanic. Dystopia isn’t where things go wrong. Dystopia is when things go wrong, and nothing can be done about it.
Anything that can’t go on forever will eventually stop. The social media barons who reeled users and business customers into a mutual hostage-taking were confident that their self-licking ice-cream cone — in which we all continued to energetically produce surpluses for them to harvest, because we couldn’t afford to leave — would last forever.
They were wrong. The important thing about the Fediverse isn’t that it’s noncommercial or decentralized — it’s that its design impedes surplus harvesting. The Fediverse is designed to keep switching costs as low as possible, by enshrining the Right Of Exit into the technical architecture of the system. The ability to leave a service without paying a price is the best defense we have against the scourge of enshittification.
(Thanks to Tim Harford for inspiring this column via an offhand remark in his kitchen a couple months ago!)
[Image ID: The Phillip Medhurst Picture Torah 397. The Israelites collect manna. Exodus cap 16 v 14. Luyken and son.]
3K notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 3 years ago
Photo
Tumblr media
More Soviet era Siberian architecture.
889 notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 3 years ago
Photo
Tumblr media Tumblr media Tumblr media Tumblr media Tumblr media Tumblr media Tumblr media Tumblr media Tumblr media
Architecture of Tomsk Photographed by marusia.savina
631 notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 3 years ago
Text
Nelle tempeste, nei temporali, nella gelida vita, nelle perdite gravi e quando sei triste, apparire sorridente e semplice – è l'arte più sublime del mondo.
L'uomo nero - Sergej A. Esenin
0 notes
petermartell-blog · 3 years ago
Photo
Tumblr media
Getting nowhere, Ben Tolman
334 notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 3 years ago
Video
The Zoetrope Effect on Vinyl                           
source
7K notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 3 years ago
Text
Tumblr media Tumblr media Tumblr media
Some Elder Scrolls Cut-outs I made. Will make more.
490 notes · View notes
petermartell-blog · 3 years ago
Text
“I think its very healthy to spend time alone. You need to know how to be alone and not be defined by another person.”
— Oscar Wilde
2K notes · View notes